Grants and Contracts Details
Description
Industry Comovement after Joining an Index:
Spillovers of Nonfundamental Effects
ABSTRACT
A substantial literature about nonfundamental, or behavioral, determinants of stock price (co)movements
has developed in recent years. The inclusion of stocks into a general market index such as the S&P 500
index has been used extensively as an experimental setting to investigate this issue. Building upon
existing theories, we investigate the existence of spillover effects of nonfundamental "index shocks" on
non-index stocks in the same industry as a stock that is added to the general index. The results ofthis
study will contribute to a better understanding of the broader economic consequences of a stock being
added to a general stock index and, consequently, the nonfundamental determinants of stock price
movements.
BACKGROUND
The Efficient Markets Hypothesis posits that asset price comovements reflect fundamental values.
That is, assuming rational investors and frictionless markets, asset prices reflect the expected present
value of future cash flows (using an appropriate discount rate). As a result, any correlations among asset
prices result from correlations of their fundamentals. However, a substantial literature about
non fundamental determinants of stock price (co)movements has developed in recent years. 1 The
inclusion of stocks into a general market index such as the S&P 500 index has been used extensively as
an experimental setting to investigate this issue for at least two reasons. First, the stock addition event
can be considered as "information-free," meaning that it has little, in any, effect on the fundamentals of
stocks added to an index.2 Second, the presence of a group oflarge institutional investors tracking the
index ensures an economically meaningful demand shock effect to the index category. In fact, numerous
studies have found evidence that fund flows into and out of well-defined index categories are correlated
with fund returns.3
Barberis and Shlefier (2003) and Barberis, Shleifer, and Wurgler (forthcoming) provide
comprehensive explanations for such nonfundamental effects. By assuming that arbitrage activities are
I See, for example, Pindyck and Rotemberg (1993), Fama and French (1993, 1995), and Froot and Dabora (1999).
2 See, for instance, Harris and Gurel (1986), Shleifer (1986), Beneish and Whaley (1996), Lynch and Mendenhall
(1997), Kau1,Mehrotra, and Morek (2000), and Wurgler and Zhuravskaya (2002).
3 To name a few, Warther (1995), Edwards and Zhang (1998), Fortune (1998), Goetzmann and Massa (2003), Cha
and Lee (2001), Edelen and Warner (2001), Karceski (2003), Goetzmann and Massa (2003), and Ling and Naranjo
(2003).
I
Status | Finished |
---|---|
Effective start/end date | 1/1/05 → 12/31/05 |
Fingerprint
Explore the research topics touched on by this project. These labels are generated based on the underlying awards/grants. Together they form a unique fingerprint.